Thursday, December 31, 2009

Rising Islamism and (Bad) Islamic Economics


Any keen observer of the Islamic world must see this. Islamism is on the rise, first and foremost in terms of identity politics of the Muslim masses. Other forms of identity have failed, and have been abandoned by the masses: Arab nationalism and socialism of Nasser and the Ba`th; ancient nationalism such as Pharonic Egypt, Babylonian Iraq, Phoenecian Lebanon, and Cyrus's Persia, etc.; and globalized westernism. Elements of all three tendencies continue, of course, but they are constantly being pushed to the margins, as a new brand of Islamism is on the rise.

When they think of rising Islamism, people (and governments) in the west tend to think mainly of violent "jihadists", as they like to call them, but that is far from accurate. My own casual observation identifies mainly two groups. The first is a group who adopt the appearance of religiosity, in dress, language, etc., but retain a true identity that is some mixture of the three aforementioned (non-Islamist) tendencies. This includes people who use religion to advance their economic objectives, or simply to fit into an increasingly religious society.

The second group is much more interesting, but it appears to be suffering an identity crisis. They seek to live according to an Islamic ideal, but quickly discover that the Islamic ideal is largely fictional. This group includes well-meaning Muslims who turn to religious studies, only to discover the irrelevance and corruption of what they had considered scholarly circles. It includes MBA-holders who decide to get into "Islamic finance", only to discover that it is a racket for enriching cynical English bankers and lawyers, along with some corrupt, gullible, or greedy Muslims.

Most importantly, the second group includes most of the masses in Egypt, Pakistan, Indonesia, Malaysia, Turkey, and elsewhere, who would like to embrace the slogan "Islam is the solution", but fail to see how that solution would work in reality. This is the greatest failure of the school of thought generally known as "Islamic Economics", which sought to develop an understanding of Political Economy from "an Islamic perspective".

Timur Kuran has written a lot about this school of thought and its failures (most of those writings were reproduced in his recent book Islam and Mammon). Timur's conclusion is that the historical and intellectual record of "Islamic economics" illustrates that Islamism has also failed. It is definitely true that the brand of mid-Twentieth Century Islamism, which is still unfortunately marketed by most formal Islamic organizations, including the Islamic Development Bank and others, have indeed failed, and failed miserably, especially in the countries where it was taken most seriously -- Pakistan, Iran and Sudan.

However, if we are interested in real economic development in the Islamic world (beyond just pumping oil and gas, erecting buildings, and selling cell phones), we cannot dismiss the rising wave of Islamism. Indeed, religious inclinations can serve as a greater social bond for a new social contract than any nationalism or western materialism.

The difficulty is this: to find or develop and workable "Islamic solution", one must abandon historical and pietist utopianism. Islamic history, from its earliest days, has never painted a rosy picture. Islamic societies prospered when they were open to learning from others: Sassanid, Byzantine, etc. The famous Prophetic tradition said: "seek knowledge (`ilm), even [if you have to go to] China", and yet our young still seek knowledge (`ilm) only by going to Saudi Arabia, Pakistan, or Egypt, centuries after the Islamic world ceased to be a main depositary of knowledge.

The result is "Islamic finance", "Islamic jeans", and "Islamic Cola", along with satellite channels that broadcast feel good televangelist speeches about Islam, and broadcasting songs about Hijab and the Prophet in between MTV-style videoclips. This pattern cannot satisfy the increasing Islamist sentiment for long. Suspicions about the Muslim Brotherhood, Hamas, and other political Islamist groups notwithstanding, it seems almost inevitable that the growing wave of Islamism will bring a wave of political Islamists to power throughout the region.

The choice is most likely restricted to one of three scenarios:

(1) If they use the current pietist/historical brands of Islamism, those Islamist groups will fail, just like their predecessors did in Pakistan, Iran, and Sudan. Advocates of western capitalism will point to that failure to advocate abanadoning the Islamist identity. The Islamists will increase in their opposition to western capitalism, arguing that the fault was not with the ideal, but with its implementation. The rift between the two groups grows until every country in the region looks like Turkey.

(2) Some may follow the Erdogan route, but that is really just western capitalism dressed in Islamist garb, and thus unlikely to serve any long-term socioeconomic goals. In the meantime, as we learned from the recent Turkish presidency campaign fallout, the secularists will not allow even some token symbolic victories to Islamists. To survive, the Islamists must make more compromises to prove that they are "moderates", but they will only be tolerated if they become effectively more secularist than the secularists.

(3) A new definition of Islamic-democratic political economy emerges. It is not clear that Muslims have the requisite political and intellectual human capital to develop such a paradigm over the course of few decades. Daunting as the task may be, this seems to be the least painful of the available options, and the one most conducive to bona fide economic and social development in the short to medium term.

By Mahmoud El-Gamal


Rating agencies, shoddy risk analysis, and sukuk


A recent article in the Wall Street Journal identifies the role played by rating agencies in perpetuating the credit boom that is currently imploding. The primary fault of investors, of course, is that they believed that credit ratings of new and unknown instruments, such as credit derivatives, are meaningful in any way. It is obvious that credit and asset-backed derivatives are signficantly different from the types of bonds that rating-agency experts are qualified to to assess (in terms of default risk).

In the case of sukuk, the silly bonds marketed as "Islamic" by rent-seekers, there are numerous legal risks that are very poorly understood, including by the lawyers and bankers who structure the instruments. The problem in this case is self-inflicted: the lawyers want to structure the instruments, e.g. lease-backed bonds or sukuk al-ijara, in such a way as to assure "Shari`a scholars" that bond-holders have material ownership of the underlying assets and receive "rent" rather than "interest". At the same time, they want to assure markets and rating agencies that the instruments are indistinguishable from conventional bonds, where the only mateiral risk is credit risk of the issuer. The rating agencies read the legalese and conclude that the lawyers are right: the "Islamic" structure is merely a fiction, and there is only credit risk. They give the sukuk the same credit rating they would give any other unsecured bond issued by the same entity (see, e.g. S&P's analysis of Qatar's Global Sukuk, where the rating was based on the soundness of the Qatari economy, without any significance lent to the asset ostensibly being leased back by the issuing SPV).

Unless and until we have a high-visibilty case of bankruptcy, we will not know with any certainty who owns what in the maze of SPVs that lawyers and structured financiers love to use. Until then, many will continue to line their pockets with legal, structuring, and advisory fees, as they congratulate themselves on "innovative Islamic products." What a shame!

By Mahmoud El-Gamal

Zakah and Waqf -- Form & Substance Revisited


Dr. Fahim Khan recently made an argument on IBFnet that we put the cart before the horse by jumping to Islamic banking and finance, which put the industry in bankers' hands, and therefore turned to satisfying historical forms of Shari`a, without any interest in substance. His prescribed cure is to turn to religious and historical Islamic institutions, Zakah and Waqf, focusing on Islamic economics, rather than merely finance -- which will take care of itself if we define proper economic objectives. I think that there is merit to this argument, but I fear that it is not sufficient.

First, and very briefly, financial considerations have been at the forefront of most economic activities nowadays. If we look at the real estate boom in Saudi Arabia, where Dr. Fahim lives, we will see that it is merely a mortar-and-steel manifestation of a financial bubble (that showed up first in the Saudi and neighboring stock markets, and in commodities, and then ultimately in the ridiculous waste of petrodollars in the building of vacant tall buildings in Dubai, Bahrain, Qatar, etc.). In the U.S., where I live, finance has also taken over much of what we do, with hedge funds and private equity firms buying and selling companies to turn a quick profit, rather than to restructure them and make them more productive.

Second, and more importantly, I fear that focusing on the historical institution of Waqf can be as detrimental to Islamic economics as focusing on sales and leases has been detrimental to Islamic finance. Moreover, the focus on Zakah is also misplaced given the narrow religious frame that real Islamic scholars (most notably, Dr. Al-Qaradawi) have imposed, despite the attempts of economists such as the late Dr. Mahmoud Abou El Saoud. Let me elaborate.

Problems with Awqaf

There is nothing distinctively Islamic about Waqf. At the advent of Islam in Arabia, there were two models of charitable trusts that the Muslims could have borrowed: the Roman and the Persian. The first texts in Sunna tell us that the first waqf in Madina was formed by one of the Medinese wealthy Jews, and then the second was by `Umar ibn Al-Khattab (r). In the second Hadith, the Prophet (p) simply told him "make it a waqf," clearly establishing that this was already a known practice. In fact, the Islamic Waqf, as the rules were later established by scholars, mimicked the Persian system. As historians have shown, this system of waqf then evolved with different rules, as scholars were very liberal in awqaf, since their essence
was charitable. In fact, however, awqaf quickly became means of circumventing inheritance rules -- to avoid division of property -- while ostensibly remaining charitable due to clauses that they became so once the waqif's genetic line ended.

Timur Kuran has written extensively on the inefficiencies of awqaf in Turkey and elsewhere in the Ottoman empire. The Iranian Bonyads continue to be a major source of monopoly power and inefficiency in the economy.

Of course, that does not mean that the trust/waqf model is inherently inferior to corporations, as Timur has argued. Indeed, one of the most powerful monopolies in the previous round of globalization around the turn of the 20th century was Standard Oil, which was a trust -- hence the U.S. has "anti-trust" rather than "anti-monopoly" laws, even when applied to corporations such as Microsoft.

Historians have traced the roots of the Anglo-American trust system to Awqaf, which King Roger II knew during his youth in Sicily. However, that model evolved in different directions, giving us much more effective trusts in the west today than the awqaf that have survived governments' attacks in the Islamic world. The evolution of the trust as an "un-corporation" might have given us a superior institution, as some legal scholars have argued recently, see Robert Sitkoff's papers on the topic. However, the Islamic world has in fact failed to make awqaf even play their own traditional role, let alone to become an engine for economic growth and development.

Thus, I fear that our focus on awqaf as a historical institution will put us in the same trap of looking at it as some kind of sacred institution, ignoring that there are no set rules for awqaf that are written in stone, and adhering again to form rather than substance.

Problems with Contemporary Zakah

Zakah is fundamentally a poverty-alleviation mechanism (the poor and destitute being the first two categories of recipients listed in the Qur'an), and therefore its role is by necessity quite restricted. In a country with limited poverty, it might turn into more general public finance, but even then restricted by scholars' categories of spending "in the way of Allah" (they include education, infrastructure building, etc.).

Those problems of spending Zakah funds notwithstanding, the biggest problem today with Zakah has to do with the collection of funds. The biggest source of Zakah funds if we were to apply the classical rules would be a percentage of oil and gas wealth (zakat al-ma`adin w al-rikaz). However, since those resources are generally nationalized, there is no point in going there!

For private individuals, there are numerous Zakah shelters. The rules of Zakah as a wealth tax was appropriate for the categories of merchants, shepherds, and farmers who possessed wealth during the Prophet's (p) time. Those rules are grossly inadequate today. Dr. Al-Qaradawi himself commented that when he visited Malaysia, he found that small farmers who produced grains and fruits paid the Zakah (zakat al-zuru` w al-thimar), but that the richer landowners who grew trees for the production of rubber paid no Zakah, since the classical rules do not include a tax on trees that did not bear fruit!

Worse, yet, today's capital for the average well-to-do Muslim may be in large part human capital (lawyers, doctors, etc.). Those can earn huge incomes, but then live in equally huge homes (Zakah exempt) and drive equally expensive cars (Zakah exempt), etc. In the end of the day, they have no gold or silver, no merchandise, no livestock, etc., and therefore pay no Zakah. The late Dr. Mohammad Al-Ghazali, and the late Dr. Abou El Saoud, tried to argue for an income Zakah, but Dr. Al-Qaradawi argued that Zakah contains a major ta`abbud (ritual worship) element, as the third pillar of Islam, and therefore did not want to apply analogical reasoning with much liberty. Needless to say, wealthy Muslims were more than happy to adopt this conservative view that allowed them to pay less!

Again, we have a problem with religious substance giving way to pietist adherence to forms. This is the general malaise of Muslims today. It is not restricted to finance.

adapted from http://elgamal.blogspot.com/2007/07/zakah-and-waqf-form-substance-revisited.html


Economic System of Islam: Dogmatist.



Islam is an entire way of life, and Allah's Guidance extends into all areas of our lives. Islam has given detailed regulations for our economic life, which is balanced and fair. Muslims are to recognize that wealth, earnings, and material goods are the property of God, and we are merely His trustees. The principles of Islam aim at establishing a just society wherein everyone will behave responsibly and honestly. The fundamental principles of the Islamic economic system are as follows:
  • Muslims are not to deal in interest. "Those who devour usury will not stand....Allah has permitted trade and forbidden usury.... Allah will deprive usury of all blessing, but will give increase for deeds of charity...." (Qur'an 2:275-6) "O you who believe! Devour not usury, doubled and multiplied. But fear Allah, that you may really prosper." (3:130) This prohibition is for all interest-based transactions, whether giving or receiving, whether dealing with Muslims or non-Muslims. It is reported that the Prophet Muhammad (peace be upon him) cursed those who pay interest, those who receive it, those who write a contract based on it, and those who witness such a contract.
  • It is forbidden to gain property or wealth by fraud, deceit, theft, or other falsehoods. "...Give just measure and weight, and do not withhold from people the things that are their due. And do not do mischief on the earth after it has been set in order. That will be best for you, if you have faith." (7:85)
  • It is particularly hateful for a guardian to take from an orphan's property. "To orphans restore their property (when they reach their age). Do not substitute your worthless things for their good ones, and do not devour their property by mixing it up with your own. For this is indeed a great sin." (4:2)
  • Forbidden are earnings from gambling, lotteries, and the production, sale, and distribution of alcohol. "O you who believe! Intoxicants and gambling, sacrificing to stones, and divination by arrows are an abomination of Satan's handiwork. Eschew such abomination, that you may prosper." (5:90)
  • It is unlawful to hoard food and other basic necessities. Everyone should take what they need and no more. "And let those who covetously withhold of the gifts which Allah has given them of His Grace, think that it is good for them. No, it will be the worse for them. Soon it will tied to their necks like a twisted collar, on the Day of Judgment. To Allah belongs the heritage of the heavens and the earth, and Allah is well-acquainted with all that you do." (3:180)
  • A Muslim should be responsible in spending money. Extravagance and waste are strongly discouraged. "[The Servants of Allah are] Those who, when they spend, are not extravagant and not stingy, but hold a just balance between those extremes." (25:67) "O Children of Adam! Wear your beautiful apparel at every time and place of prayer. Eat and drink, but waste not by excess, for Allah loves not the wasters." (7:31)
  • Payment of Zakat (alms). "And they have been commanded no more than this: to worship Allah, offering Him sincere devotion, being true in faith. To establish regular prayer, and to give zakat. And that is the religion right and straight." (98:5) Every Muslim who owns wealth, more than a certain amount to meet his or her needs, must pay a fixed rate of Zakat to those in need. Zakat is a means of narrowing the gap between the rich and the poor, and to make sure that everyone's needs are met.
  • Muslims are encouraged to give constantly in charity. "Your riches and your children may be but a trial. Whereas Allah, with Him is the highest reward. So fear Allah as much as you can, listen and obey, and spend in charity for the benefit of your own souls. And those saved from the selfishness of their own souls, they are the ones that achieve prosperity." (64:15-16) The Prophet Muhammad once said that "nobody's assets are reduced by charity."


Importance Of Economics For Entrepreneurs


Entrepreneur's job is to combine the factors of production. Knowledge of economic laws and principles enables him to have an ideal combination of the different factors of production. In ideal combination entrepreneurs gets maximum returns from input because the cost per unit is minimum and the consumer gets the goods at a low price as a result the demand for output increases because a number of people who can effort to purchase increases.

Its study helps them in the fixation of the prices of their produced commodities through cost and demand analysis and as a result they can get more profit and sometimes accommodates a large number of buyers.

Study of economics helps them in framing their business, policy and making effective decision related to their enterprises. Its studies also help them to solve their operational and management problems.

Economics guide the entrepreneurs in allocating the resources in different productive cannels in a rational way. This reduces waste and helps in getting maximum return.

Its study helps them in improving the efficiency of workers through different incentives such as increasing wage rates, improving working conditions and providing other facilities.

Economics guide consumers to distribute their income in purchasing of different commodities in such a way that they can satisfy their maximum number of wants within the given resources.

Its study helps them to distinguish b/w the productive and un-productive expenditures. In this way they can control their expenses and disposing off they're saving to d/f productive channels, which create a source of income for them in future.

By the study of economics businessmen learn the procedures and practices followed in trade and commerce. They get information about banking, monetary policy of government which helps them to organize and adjust their business activities and increase the margin of profit and improve the quality of his goods and services.

Economic guides the statesmen in locating the causes of socio-economic social and economic and problems and to take correct measures to solve them for the welfare of the nation for e.g. unemployment is a social as well as an economical problem which creates disturbance in the country and brings up many social evils. Study of economics helps the statesmen in locating its causes and provides suitable measures to solve this problem.

Economics also enables the statesmen to understand the working process of the economic system and analyzing its issues. Its study guides them to make such economic policies through which distribution of national wealth can be distributed equally among all the members of the society.

Statesmen get acquainted through economics with the working mechanism of economic variables such as production, consumption, saving, investment etc. Knowledge of such things helps them a lot in taking steps to ensure a prosperous life of the people.

By: Khalid Aziz


Islamic Economic System


The followers of Islam are required to lead a material life in such a way that it becomes a source of happiness and prosperity in the existing world. It proves to be source of benevolence for them in the next world. With this point in view we now define Islamic economic system in line with the technical definitions given for other system.

“Islamic economic system consists of institutions, organizations

And the social values by which natural, human and man made

Resources are used to produce, exchange, distribute and consume

Wealth/goods and services under the guiding principles of Islam

To achieve FALAH in this world and also after it”

From the definition it is clear that Muslims are required to follow the principles of Islam in all aspects of an economy. For example production of wealth should take place strictly with in the limits described by Islam to find that ultimate consumption pattern of the people is evolved in line with the injunctions of Islam.

The silent features or the main characteristics of the economic system of Islam are as follows.

Islam gives a unique concept of ownership or right to private property. According to this concept every thing belongs to Allah and the people are trustees of what is being given to them by Allah. Thus, they are allowed to own and use property earned by them in accordance with the guidelines of Islam. This shows that Islam recognizes the individual’s right to private property and it permits ownership of all type of property.

Basic principles laid down in Islam for the consumption and investment of private property are as follows:

One has to distinguish between HALAL and HARAM in the pursuit of his/her earning or in the production and consumption of wealth.

Parading of ones wealth or ostentation is not allowed.

A property cannot be used against public interest.

Extravagance or spending lavishly on consumer goods and also miserliness on the contrary, is forbidden.

Real/money capital cannot be used for gambling.

People are not allowed to lend their money capital to earn interest.

Payment of Zakat and Ushar is compulsory and obligatory and therefore evasion in this regard would be illegal.

In an Islamic society people are not allowed to satisfy their wants by the way they choose, as it is their in other economic systems. According to Islamic principles, people are allowed to consume necessaries and comforts in life and luxuries are not allowed to be used in any way because this is against the concept of TAQWA. Hence Islam shows HALAL and HARAM. Only HALALS are required to be consumed and not the HARAM ones.

Price mechanism plays a key role in carrying out the production process in an Islamic society. To start with, prices of factors of production i.e. land, labour, capital and organizations are determined in the factor market through free competition between the owners of the factors and the entrepreneurs.

In the Islamic society, entrepreneurs are free to initiate, organize and run any business they choose and in any form they like, but only those goods and services will be produced whose production is allowed by Islam. Following types of production of wealth and the business thereof is not allowed by Islam and it cannot operate in an Islamic society.

1. Production of drugs, alcoholic drinks, gambling, prostitution, lottery, music and dance etc.

2. Lending and borrowing on interest.

3. Black marketing, hoarding, smuggling etc.

Islam does not advocate equal distribution of wealth in the sense that all individuals should have the same or equal means from livelihood and that there should be no difference in their economic status in society. It favors fair (not equal) distribution of wealth in the sense that it should not be confined to any particular section of the society. It is therefore required that wealth should spread out in the community and all individuals should have equal opportunities to seek employment or to do a business of their own choice.

Zakat/Ushar is a major source of revenue for the government in an Islamic state. It is a compulsory levy, on cattle, crops, merchandise, gold, silver and cash. It is a levy, not on income but on total wealth, which has been in the possession of an owner for one year. Whether the owner has utilized his wealth in production or not, he is liable to pay Zakat every year in the month of Rajab or after it.

An Islamic economy is always an interest free economy. Therefore, the earning of income an interest is totally forbidden in an Islamic state.

Islam advises its followers to invest their money capital in different forms of business organizations like sole proprietorship, partnership etc. In sole proprietorship entrepreneurs invest their own money capital to earn profit, while partner’s pool up their capital for investment to run the form of business called partnership. The profit earned thereof is distributed according to an agreement signed between the two parties. In the case of loss in business, the whole loss is borne by the person who makes capital investment while the other person loses his labor only.

The amount of capital in an Islamic state depends on the amount of saving. Therefore, to increase the amount of capital for economic growth in the Islamic economy it is absolutely necessary that (i) people should endeavor to increase their income, (ii) they should spend their income very carefully, (iii) there should be a sound security system to enable people to earn wealth freely and easily.

An Islamic government mostly assumes administrative responsibilities to achieve economic growth and stability in the state.

From the silent features of Islamic economic system it becomes evident that the system meets quite naturally the material and spiritual requirements of human beings as opposed to capitalism and communism wherein only the material wants are satisfied. Under this system, basic material needs in life i.e. food, shelter, clothing, health, education etc are provided to the people and the needy in particular. As far as spiritual needs are concerned, they are provided through spiritual values.

By:Khalid Aziz


The Issue of Riba in Islamic Faith and Law


Perhaps one of the most difficult issues in Islamic concern for fairness in business dealings is its prohibition of business transactions that call for charging riba (usury and interest). Riba, in its Qur`anic meaning, means paying money for the use of money. Muslims have struggled with the problem ever since the Qur`an categorically denounced riba. From the Islamic perspective, with its bias towards fair distribution of wealth and social justice, the Qur`an's strictures against riba have implications for international political economy. The issue also confronts devout Muslim business people as they struggle to make their investments religiously and morally legitimate.

This essay will analyze the controversy around riba as a prime example of how Muslims engage in ethical reasoning about business practice. It will show that ethical judgements in Islam amalgamate cultural elements derived from the particular experience of Muslims living in a specific place and time, as verified by the timeless universal norms derived from the scriptural sources like the Qur`an and the Tradition (Sunna), which themselves possess common elements applicable to all humans as humans.

Although the business world today is moving towards globalization in which small businesses are going to be further marginalized, the paragon of business ethics in the Muslim world as well as the West remains a devout individual who exhibits unusual sense of ethical-religious responsibility towards the higher goals set by his/her religious teachings. To dismiss this dimension from discussions about the business world today is equivalent to saying that the highly technicalized business world is moving at a pace uncontrollable by human beings and that no human conscience is able to direct the moral consequences of wealth-generating enterprises, however exploitative or corruptive they might appear to morally conscious individual or group of individuals. The following case illustrates the ethical dilemma presented by the Qur`anic stricture against paying and charging interest in business dealings.

A Religious Ethical Dilemma for a Muslim Businessman

Mr. Kamaluddin, a highly successful businessman, was faced with an ethical dilemma of a religious kind when he bought his company some twenty-three years ago. At first he did not let the owner of the property know that he had an ethical and religious problem with a transaction that involved him paying interest, because he was concerned that the seller would have factored that interest into his selling price. So after Mr. Kamaluddin had negotiated the price, he told the owner that he make a down payment, and then cover the rest in installments over a period of time. However, he could not pay interest on the unpaid balance because that was not allowed by his religion. The owner suggested that the selling price be increased to cover the interest. Mr. Kamaluddin argued that it would amount to the same thing as paying interest and in good conscience he could not justify that. He also made it clear that if this were not acceptable then he would simply not proceed with the transaction. At this point, the owner agreed not to charge the interest. Mr. Kamaluddin finalized the deal and bought the business.

In this case the amount of the interest was not significant and the owner was not going to lose much money. Nevertheless, it is hard to predict what the owner would have done had the amount of the interest been significant. And because the stakes are often much higher, the prohibition on interest-taking presents serious problems to Muslim business people. While Mr. Kamaluddin had enough resources to make the down payment, those Muslims who don't, face a quandary. Either they would have to apply for a loan to an interest-charging bank or they would simply have to give up an opportunity to start a new business.

Conscience and social responsibility in Islam

Mr. Kamaluddin's case underscores one of the fundamental value differences in business practice between Muslims and their counterparts in the West, namely, the ethical status of interest related transactions. Religious rulings related to the charging, paying and taking of interest in Islamic legal tradition have been at the center of ethical deliberations among Muslims for many centuries. Around the world, mainstream Islamic opinion continues to regard interest as an impediment to social justice. As a result, the question of whether interest is a legitimate financial instrument or not remains an important issue of conscience. In the Islamic tradition, human acts have a direct impact upon the development of conscience, the source of determining the rightness or wrongness of human undertakings. The conscience must be constantly guarded against being corrupted. For when the conscience of individuals becomes corrupted as a result of neglecting ethical matters related to the production of daily sustenance, there remains no moral safeguard to prevent these individuals from engaging into more serious acts that would lead to the destruction of the very fabric of social relations founded upon divinely ingrained sense of justice and fairness.

Islam, as it developed in the regions inhabited by other monotheistic faiths like Judaism, Christianity and Zoroastrianism, shared an ethos of public order founded upon justice. It required the practice of a minimum of moral virtues intended to be a kind of "rule of life," to foster a sense of social responsibility. In the Islamic view, both reflection and intention must precede all human acts which infringe upon the spiritual and temporal well being of others. To guide such reflection and inform such intention, Islam has developed a cohesive body of ethical reflection. Islam, the third and last of the Abrahamic religions to emerge, literally means "submission to God's will". It was proclaimed by Muhammad (born 570 C.E.), the Prophet of Islam and the founder of Islamic public order during the 600s in Mecca, Arabia.

Along with certain rules, which were practical and material, temporary and external, Muslim jurists explicitly decreed various permanent restrictions designed to discipline both the body (rules about lawful foods and earning, about dress and public behavior) and the mind (prohibited subjects of thought and conversation that led to the corruption of conscience). In addition, Islam required certain expiatory works of charity to compensate for the sins of omission and commission. These works were intended primarily to inculcate a sense of social responsibility. Whereas the ritual acts, whether performed publicly in a group or privately, were the homage humankind paid to God and were intended to affect the conscience of the practicing believer, commercial engagements were closely tied to the notions of interpersonal justice and were intended to affect public behavior. In this latter sense, the rites are instruments provided by God for developing the conscience in the direction of greater social responsibility.

Islamic juridical discourse on the market

Islam required a good public order in which spiritual interests were organically related to individual material well-being. Hence the law of the marketplace was given almost equal weight with the regulations connected with acts of worship in the mosque. This emphasis on economic relations in the context of commercial markets was not suprising, given that Mecca was the most important trading center of western and central Arabia. Meccans played a dominant role in the creation of a culture that nurtured the cultivation and development of socioeconomic system based on Islamic justice.

The market mechanism is an integral part of the Islamic economic system because the institution of private property depends on it for its operation. It also provides the consumers to express their desires for the production of goods of their liking by their willingness to pay the price. But the profit motive that is essential for the operation of free enterprise, if not controlled, can also become a tool of greed and violate the Islamic goals of social and economic justice and equitable distribution of income and wealth. The strictures against usury in the Qur`an can be seen in the clear distinction Islam makes between legitimate trade with profit motive and unchecked individual greed to increase one's possessions manifold without engaging in precarious trade in a market economy. According to Muslim jurists:

The law in order for the people to benefit mutually permits buying and selling. There is no doubt that this can also be a cause of injustice, because both buyer and seller desire more profit and the Lawgiver has neither prohibited profit nor has He set limits to it. He has, however, prohibited fraud and cheating and ascribing to a commodity attributes that it does not possess.

The main concern of the Islamic public order was not so much collective interest as individual justice in transactions that had to be protected outside of close friendship and family ties. It was expected that, contrary to the claims of tribal kinship and noble family lineage that determined social relations in pre-Islamic Arabia, most human relations under Islam would take the form of contractual relations rather than be determined in advance by social status. Many provisions in the law attempted to back those who were weak in one way or another against the strong who might take advantage of them. While on the whole, faith in Islam constituted ten parts, only one part was related to the God-human relationship and claimed the status of a common universal obligation. The remaining nine parts were related to human relationships, and determined by contractual responsibilities and specific social and cultural experience.

Muslim juridical writings give detailed rulings related to the acquisition and disposal of private and business property and purchase and sale of merchandise. The underlying principle operative in market law is twofold: the autonomy of individual to own productive resources to further her or his economic interest, and the protection of the consumer from harm. The pursuit of individual economic interest was to be regulated within a communitarian ethic requiring the individual to take the competing interests of the community at large as morally binding. Therefore, any individual business undertaking seen to cause harm to the moral and spiritual fabric of the society was to be condemned and prohibited.

The protection of the consumer was regulated through the principle of non-maleficence (al-darar al-muhtamal). This principle required that resource-owners could not seek to cause harm to the buyers by using false information and other means to raise sales. Hence, deceptive advertising was regarded as morally wrong and legally punishable. The principle of public interest (maslahah) required that free mutual consent of the buyer and the seller be regarded as a necessary condition for any business transaction. The Qur`an provides the grounds for the ruling: "O believers, consume not your goods between you in vanity, except there be trading, by your agreeing together". Individual freedom in negotiating business transactions was recognized in the directive given by the Prophet: "Leave people alone for God provides them sustenance through each other". Thus freedom of enterprise leaves much of the production and distribution of goods and services to individuals or voluntarily constituted groups. However, even this otherwise absolute freedom was regulated by the legal principle of public interest that requires that faithful Muslims produce more good than harm.

The integration of ethics and law was most clearly worked out in Islamic economics. The need to regulate an economic system that would be compatible with Islamic concern for redistribution of wealth and social justice required Muslim jurists to resort to legal doctrines and practical rules where the validity of their rulings against certain forms of usury received judicious legal elaboration. The apparent meaning of those verses of the Qur`an that spoke about the prohibition of usury in a straightforward manner were developed through the legal principles and rules, case by case, to create the framework for a morally accountable financial exchange. The nature of this process of legal and ethical construction is taken up next.

Shari`ah and the Emergence of Principles from Cases

Islamic ethics, mediated through God's will, is an integral part of Islamic law: the Shari`ah. The Shari`ah is the divinely ordained blueprint for human conduct, which was inherently and essentially religious. It enjoys comprehensive scope, for it encompasses judgments of public interest and equity which link the overall prosperity of the community in this life and the next. The end of humanity is happiness, and this is attained fully through the rewards of God on the Day of Judgment for everything that humans do to improve the quality of spiritual and moral and material life of humanity.

Islamic jurisprudence (fiqh) was developed to determine normative Islamic conduct as detailed in the Shari`ah. The legal precedents and principles provided by the Qur`an and Sunna were used to develop an elaborate system of rules of jurisprudence. By the middle of the eighth century, Islamic jurists had developed and laid down a legal theory to allow a judge or a mufti to find out in all circumstances what was the legal and moral action. The two sources for deriving authoritative guidance were the Qur`an, the basic scripture of Islam, and the Sunna, the normative directives deduced from the Prophet Muhammad's own actions. Two further resources in Sunni law were provided by the consensus (ijma`) of the scholars of legal tradition, and by a method of analogical deduction (qiyas). Sunni jurists used qiyas to project a new ruling from a known ruling by using data furnished by the Qur`an and the Sunna. Al-Shafi`i (d. 820), a rigorous legal thinker, systematically and comprehensively linked these four sources to extend Shari`ah to cover all possible contingencies. In the Shi`ite jurisrudence, the methodology of their founding scholar and Imam Ja`far al-Sadiq (d. 748) allowed greater use of human reason in deriving the entire system of the Shari`ah. Shi`ite jurists perfected the principle of the correlation between a judgment derived from reason and the one promulgated by the Qur'an and the Sunna, thereby giving human intuitive reason a substantial role in deriving legal decisions at all times. The `rule of correlation' (qa`idat al-mulazama) in Shi`ite law allows the jurists to infer the rulings in the Shari`ah from the sole verdict of reason.

Legal scholars and other administrative officials exercising judicial powers usually issued judgments of public interest, convenience or similar considerations. Duties and right actions that were not mentioned in the Qur`an and Sunna were to be determined by the exercise of independent personal judgment of lawyers. As developed in the classical Islamic legal theory (usul al-fiqh), justifications in religious-moral action consists of a dialectic between judgments (fatawa) in specific cases and the generalizations derived from effective causes (`ilal) in cases in the light of which generalizations themselves are modified. Hence, to derive a specific ethical judgment - for example, that an act of distribution of surplus wealth among the needy is obligatory - is to confirm that it satisfies a certain description of the religious-moral concept of justice according to one's belief in social responsibility. Social responsibility as part of the generalizable command to be just could then be applied to other acts.

The criterion of social responsibility has made it necessary for Islamic jurists to nuance the stringency of moral rules. In contemporary Islamic thinking, human conduct is to be determined in terms of how much legal weight is borne by a particular rule, and whether a rule renders a given practice obligatory or merely recommended. For instance, bribery is ethically and legally forbidden. But if it becomes necessary under an unjust system in order to influence a decision leading to the betterment of the community, then Islamic law excuses it after a careful risk-benefit analysis. The underlying principle in deciding such cases was the proportion of benefit as compared to harm to the well being of the community. Some rules are categorical. For example, cases involving blatant moral-spiritual corruption are excluded from risk-benefit analysis. Another factor in determining the weight of a rule is whether it is to be enforced by penalties in the courts because it occurs in Muslim territory, or whether it is to be left to God's judgment in the hereafter because it occurs outside. Thus, for instance, transactions involving selling or buying of alcohol are regarded as illicit and punishable by the Shari`ah courts when they occur within Muslim communities. However, when a Muslim businessman living in the West sometimes has to entertain his non-Muslim clients with alcohol while abstaining himself, his action, although sinful in itself, is regarded as being beyond the jurisdiction of the Shari`ah court.

Reason and Revelation in Islamic Moral Reasoning

In recent years, attempts have been made to engage Muslim scholars in the ongoing debate in the area of business ethics in the West. At the center of this debate is the role of ethical principles and rules in the moral assessment of an action in Western thinking. Such assessment can be developed from at least four different perspectives: those of the agent, the act itself, the end, and the consequences. They offer different viewpoints about the meaning and nature of moral principles and rules as they are applied to different types of moral dilmmas. In fact, many disputes in applied ethics in the West stem from disputes about the generalizability and applicability of more than one of these normative principles that function as action-guides, categorizing actions as morally required, prohibited, or permitted. Moreover, there exists the great variety of principle-based approaches that focus on general principles as sources of rules, and rules that specify type of prohibited, required, or permitted actions before any particular judgments can be derived in cases dealing with questionable business practices.

While this conceptual apparatus is helpful, it does not enable Westerners to delineate the pattern of Islamic moral reasoning. Without adequate training in the Islamic legal sciences, especially legal theory, one cannot pinpoint the principles and the rules that Muslim jurists utilize to justify and assess moral-legal decisions within their own cultural environment. The process has combined revelation and reason. The convergence between the divine command that human beings must treat each other justly and the rational cognition of justice being good encouraged Islamic jurists to formulate specific moral-legal judgments first and then to search for principles that can be generalized and then applied to new cases. The method, refined over centuries, yields certitude in moral judgment. By working back and forth between legal doctrines and rules, on the one hand, and analogical reasoning based on paradigm cases, on the other, Muslim jurists are able to resolve ethical dilemmas that face the community in dealing with immediate questions about economic issues: banking, taking interest, advertising, and so on. The practical judgments or legal opinions, known as fatawa, reflect the insights of a jurist who has been able to connect cases to an appropriate set of linguistic and rational principles and rules that provide keys to a valid conclusion of a case under consideration.

This pattern of moral reasoning should not be seen as a lock-step deductive model. The Qur`an uses the word al-ma`ruf (the "commonly known" paradigms) for the generalized principles which must be inferred from concrete ethical practice of everyday life. It made no attempt to lay down a comprehensive moral system because it treated morality as "the known," al-ma`ruf. Al-ma`ruf, in the meaning of moral behavior in the Qur`an, signifies "goodness," a "good quality or action," gentleness in any action, or deed, of which goodness is known by reason and by the revelation." Muslim jurists have been working out practical ways of carrying out more efficient proceedings in view of the changed circumstances of commercial life, without setting aside the more idealistic provisions of the law as basic norms. The justification provided by these jurists was to argue that there is a correlation between "known" moral convictions and God's purposes as mentioned in revelation.

Market Ethics and the Charging of Interest

In general, it can be said that in every ethical situation Islamic juridical tradition seeks to address and accommodate the demands of justice and public good. Perhaps one of the most difficult issues to test the Islamic concern for fairness in business dealings was its early prohibition of business transactions that called for charging interest (riba). Often translated by "usury", this term in its Qur`anic meaning, refers to using money to buy the use of money. Muslims have struggled with the problem of interest ever since the Qur`an categorically denounced it, and have not achieved agreement among themselves. Some jurists have interpreted the Qur`anic prohibition to permit exceptions as cases required in different contexts. There have been a number of rulings issued at different times in the history of Islamic jurisprudence making a distinction between `usury' (riba) and `interest' to circumvent the categorical prohibition. Other scholars believe that there is a difference between Muslim and non-Muslim financial institutions, allowing Muslims to receive interest from the latter institutions while prohibiting it from the former.

This lack of unanimity reflects a common but misleading practice among Muslims: sweeping larger questions about the nature of divine revelation under the rug when it comes to addressing interest and usury and other major ethical problems exacerbated by the introduction of laissez faire economics. This uncritical approach to the normative sources has deep roots in the theology of revelation in Islam. Briefly stated, there are two major trends about the meaning and relevance of revelation for Muslims. According to one, Islamic revelation in its present form was `created' in time and space. As such, it reflects historical circumstances of that original divine command. According to the other view, revelation was `uncreated' and hence its current form is not conditioned by place and time. Most devout Muslims reject any hints that the interpretation of revelation reflects cultural or historical variables. In the wake of both quantitative and qualitative change in the modern Muslim economies, the question arises as to how far traditional readings of the revelation are relevant in assessing the negative and positive limits governing the present economic system? It is this critical theological question with drastic ramifications for the overall status of normative tradition that is usually swept under the rug.

Rather than peek further under this rug, I will consider some of this historical and theological issues connected with the institution of riba. At the time that the Prophet emerged in Mecca, transactions with a fixed time limit and payment of interest (riba), as well as speculations of all kinds, formed an essential element in the highly developed regional system of trade in Arabia. A debtor who could not repay the capital (money or goods) with the accumulated interest at the time it became due was given an extension of time in which to pay, but at the same time the sum due was doubled. The practice was prevalent during the early part of the Prophet's mission in Mecca before he migrated to Medina in 622 CE, where he denounced it. Like other social reforms the Prophet introduced into his growing community, the prohibition against interest was introduced in stages in the Qur`an. It began with a caution: "O believers, devour not usury (riba) doubled and redoubled, and fear you God." Later, , the prohibition was proclaimed in no uncertain terms:

Those who devour usury (riba) shall only rise as one whom Satan strikes with his touch; that is because they say: `selling is like usury.' God has permitted selling and forbidden usury…God blots out usury, but freewill offerings He augments with interest. God does not love any guilty unbeliever… O believers, be aware of your duties, and give up usury that is outstanding, if you are believers. But if you do not, then beware that God and His prophet shall war with you. If you repent, you shall have your principal, without doing an injustice or suffering an injustice. If any one is in difficulty let there be a delay till he is able to pay, but it is better for you to give freewill offerings if you are wise.

It is important to note that instructions about usury are connected to the message about "freewill offerings" (sadaqat), encouraging people to "spend in the path of God." The Qur`an compares and contrasts two practices: usury earned without giving anything in return, and charity given without taking anything in return. Measured in risk-benefit terms, the evil effects of usury surpass by far the good effects of charity. The Qur`an indicates that the practice of usury leads to the concentration of wealth in few hands, giving these people power over the less fortunate in society: "And they accepted usury even though they had been forbidden to do so; and they devoured and misappropriated the goods and monies of others in their greed." The practice is seen to lead to social unrest and corruption because the rich become richer as a result of reckless profiteering, whereas the poor remain poor: "That which you entrust to commercial organizations with a view to making profit will not be increased by God; nor will it increase your sustenance…Corruption appears on land and sea because of the evil that human hands have done…". Clearly, the Qur`an regards usury a practice of unbelievers. It requires, as a test of belief, that it be abandoned. The Prophetic traditions which elaborate the Qur`anic passages declare that taking interest on loans is one of the gravest of sins. All who take part in transactions involving interest are cursed, and the guilty are threatened with hell. Various kinds of punishment are described.

The Qur`anic denunciations of usury were occasioned by the needs of a developing community faced with socio-economic imbalances. But such denunciations were not consistently absolute. The Qur`an sometimes softens its position on a matter of interpersonal justice it has fulminated against just before, recognizing the human conditions that prompt such behavior. At other times, the Prophet, as its interpreter, moderated the Qur`anic stance by providing exceptions to the overall prohibition. The case of usury points to this confrontation between revelation and social inertia in the early community. In spite of all the deterrent threats voiced in the Qur`an, some jurists foresaw that transactions involving interest would prevail. In pre-modern judicial decisions, gold and silver were generally regarded as items capable of riba. A number of traditions show that the severe prohibition of usury was moderated by reference to the changed circumstances of a transaction involving specific items and the way they exchanged hands in active trade. In general, Muslim jurists developed cases to permit exceptions to the categorical prohibition in the Qur`an. The cases were reported in the traditions that were open to various interpretations. There were monetary transactions that led to principles that now govern when and where interest may be accepted. For instance, some Muslims practiced money exchange during the Prophet's life time. They asked the Prophet if this was alright. The Prophet said: "If it is from hand to hand (yadan bi-yadin, that is, immediately), there is no harm in it; but if it is delayed (nasa'an) it is not right." Some jurists extrapolated these traditions to maintain the view that riba consists only in the increase of original amount of a loan in a business agreement with a fixed period (dayn); others opined that there is no riba if the transfer of ownership takes place immediately. In other words, interest was to be permitted if transfer of ownership took place at once.

Contemporary attitudes towards interest (riba)

Because the rulings inferred by earlier jurists were not strictly uniform, there now exists a variety of views regarding the permissibility of charging interest in the buying and selling of goods. Outside of precious metals there remain differences of opinion about the items that are liable to usury ordinances. Thus, for instance, should all business dealings in things of the same kind be considered capable of riba? The opinions vary according to the documentation used to deduce juridical decision. Some argue that interest is permitted if the transfer of ownership of goods capable of riba takes place immediately. This is also known as riba al-fadl (`immediate' credit), which occurs in a contract of sales when there is an increase in the terms of exchange themselves. The more strict Muslims limit riba to the exchange of goods of same kind in equal quantities in accordance with a tradition that says: `Gold for gold, silver for silver, wheat for wheat, barley for barley, dates for dates, salt for salt, each kind for each kind, in hand. He who increases or asks for an increase commits riba, alike whether he gives or takes.' In the case of loans, which occasioned the Qur`anic prohibition of interest in the first place, it is forbidden to make a condition that a larger quantity shall be returned without regard to the kind of article. This is known as riba al-nasi`a (`delayed' credit) which entails a fixed increase in the amount of money over a time period. This kind of riba is the main source of contention.

The law regarding interest in lending is formally more strict. Muslims are prohibited either from taking or paying interest. Much of the Islamic law of contract is aimed at enforcing this prohibition of usury and risk (maysir). Riba in a loan exists not only when one insists upon the repayment of larger quantity, but also if any advantage at all is demanded. Therefore, it can even be forbidden to draw up a bill of exchange (suftaja) because the vendor, who is regarded as the creditor, reaps the advantage of avoiding the cost of transport. To be sure, many merchants used bills of exchange in the Muslim middle ages. But they were always conscious that a direct breach of the prohibition of usury was a grave sin.

Remembering such strict interpretations, conscientious Muslims to this day therefore not infrequently refuse to take bank interest. It is accurate to say that riba has operated in a negative manner. The thrust of the debate over riba has centered on the definition of the term, and has included little by way of a positive construction of a viable alternative in the contemporary financial world. The oil boom changed the picture of money flow radically, and one urgent problem facing the Arab and Islamic world was how to utilize effectively the petrodollars without openly flouting the Shari`ah. The question of riba emerged again, but in a different context. For many concerned with its prohibition, the premise was that riba simply meant interest, and loans for interest could consequently not be accepted. Still, the importance of riba-based commerce and its requirement to charge interest have given rise to a number of methods to evade the prohibition. Some Sunni schools and the Shi`ites have recognized such methods of evasion in their discussion about the purpose of divinely ordained restrictions. In applied jurisprudence, these methods are not seen as contrary to the strict enforcement of the prohibition. Legal interpreters argue that two firm principles-"Necessity overrides prohibition" and "No harm and harrassment in Islam"-provide a reason to take into consideration the situational aspects (mawdu`at) of the original prohibition, to the extent that these two principles reflect the effective causes (`ilal) and inner significance (maqasid) of the Qur`anic ordinance. For example, if the categorical prohibition of interest has an adverse impact upon those who are manipulated in society, it may fail the test imposed by "Necessity overrides prohibition"; if one manoeuvers carefully to make interest fall within the acceptable limits , it may meet the test required by the rule "No harm and no harrassment." The case of deferred sales (buyu` al-`ajal) presses this line of interpretation farther. Where the delivery of the item or the payment of its price is deferred to a later date, there is no certainty nor even a strong probability that such a sale would lead to evil. Hence, if A sells his car to B for $10,000 with the price being payable in six months' time, and then A buys the same car for $8,000 from B with the price being payable immediately, this transaction in fact amounts to a loan of $8,000 to B on which he pays an interest of $2,000 after six months. From a legal viewpoint, there is a strong probability that this sale would lead to riba although there remains enough uncertainty that some jurists have regarded this type of transaction to be valid and legally binding. The uncertainty concerns whether the arrangement is actually exploitative. For if two businessmen have agreed, then it might be legitimate for the one who is to profit by the consequences of the present deal to be bound to share his profit in a complementary future deal.

Still, more strict jurists continue to regard any loan contract specifying a fixed return to the lender as immoral and illegal, regardless of the purpose for which a loan is sought, its amount and, or the prevailing institutional framework. The reason is that a distinction made in the loan operation by those who justify this operation, between the money on which the contract is made and the operation of lending itself is actually money rewarding money,which is unacceptable under the Shari`ah. This vocal minority in juridical opinion takes the Qur`anic prohibition as categorical, and hence, not open to any further debate or discussion. There is little doubt that in the case cited for this study, Mr. Kamaluddin's religious tenets were governed by the directives received from the latter group of scholars.

In general, it is safe to assume that majority of the Muslim businesses have come to recognize a fait accompli in dealing with interest-based transactions. Devout Muslims may remain hesitant to invest their money in the international stock market, but continue to avail themselves of modern banking with its religiously questionable practice of charging or paying interest. Most businesspeople simply consent to the western model as long as the financial institution happens to be non-Muslim. And some jurists regard banking with interest permissible, as long as, a person does not negotiate the interest and the bank is non-Muslim. Others seek to justify such excusatory thinking. Some leading Sunni jurists in Egypt defend their positive rulings on bank interest by regarding the modern bank interest as something different than the riba (usury) forbidden in the Qur`an. Their judgment rests on the ordinary lexical meaning of the term riba, which literally and simply means "increase" (ziyadah). They argue that since not every increase or profit is unlawful in the Shari`ah, the Qur`anic text remains open to further extrapolation as to what type of increase God intends to forbid. Another tactic is used by Islamic banking institutions in many countries, including traditionally Muslim countries like Algeria and United Arab Emirates. They maintain their economic viability by describing themselves using the Islamic legal concept of "partnership for profit and loss" (mudaraba). There are basically three parties to the "partnership": the depositor (mudarib), the entrepreneur-investor (mudarab) or agent (`amil) and the bank which is intermediary between the depositer and the entrepreneur, as well as the agent of the owner of capital deposited in its safes. In this form of organization, all the parites to the mudaraba share in the profit and losses of the enterprises.

Conclusion

Despite efforts to evade it, the prohibition of interest remains a key element in the Islamic vision of a socially responsible economy, and an important element in Islamic business practice. In the last few decades of the twentieth century, according to a report by the Institute of Islamic Banking and Insurance, as many as 150 Islamic banking institutions manage $100 billion in the Muslim countries and abroad. There is a huge market demand for religiously guided investing among Muslims. Committees of Muslim jurists are consulted to decide what companies are Qur`an-safe (i.e., for example, do not sell alcohol, pork products, tobacco or charge interest on loans) for investment. Interest in Islamic investment is growing, with international stock markets launching their own Islamic market index to track Qur`an-safe stocks. The influence of Islamic ethics extends further. Besides ruling out certain items as forbidden, the Shari`ah (Muslim religious law) also governs how much debt a company can carry and how much it can earn from interest. From the Islamic perspective, with its bias towards fair distribution of wealth and social justice, the Qur`an's strictures against riba remains at the heart of the Muslim individual as well as national financial institutions in international economic activity.

The prohibition of interest may become an important benchmark of justice in international political economy. As the world economies move closer to integration there is a growing consensus in the international community to move towards a more or less transcultural framework of ethical principles and rules. What is needed is a meta-ethics, a way for the different cultures and religions of the world to interpret their norms and practices to each other. From a normative Islamic point of view, the aim of this dialogical mode should be to engage theologians, scholars and policy makers in the world economic system to search for better ways of redestributing wealth and preserving social justice across nations. This normative focus clearly is evident in Islamic jurisprudence regarding the charging or paying of interest. When the Qur`an banned transactions involving interest, the purpose was to protect financially weak in one way or another against the wealthy who might take advantage of them. The attitude which dominated Islamic jurists was fear of arbitrariness in the decisions of those who held financial and political power. It is an appropriate attitude today.

The Islamic position is an important contribution to international business ethics, for it is supported by a general cross-cultural moral belief that the poor ought to be protected as well as a specific revelation within Islam that regards interest as a form of disregard for the downtrodden in society. All cultures share certain moral principles like beneficence or nonmaleficence. All require rules like truthfulness in advertising as an essential element in regulating morally responsible merchant-consumer relationship. The Islamic prohibition of interest therefore seems to be an extension of the ethical requirement that human beings must treat each other fairly, rather than an obstruction to commerce.

By Dr. Abdulaziz Sachedina,
University of Virginia


Friday, May 8, 2009

Divert some of Income for the Future



When you save? Usually the average person will say that they will save money if there is more. And strange, they very rarely have more money. And consequently, They rarely save.

So, when in fact the time is right to save money? The answer is the first time you receive money. Should be, you are making plans to set aside a few percent of income to save.

Initially it will be very difficult to do this, but if can be adapted will become easy. Even if we occasionally see the savings we balance, we usually will be more motivated to save more and more.

Moreover, in the next day, if the savings it really useful for us, so will infinite value that happens.

So, start planning your financial future starting now. Tung Desem Waringin been set aside to give advice to 20% for investment income or saving. If you are having difficulties, you can start with 10% of first. After that new added little by little.

If this routine you do every month, then when you are not able to work again, saving your investment may be able to pay your life.


Tuesday, May 5, 2009

Sisihkan Pendapatan untuk Masa Depan


Kapankah anda menabung? Biasanya rata-rata orang Indonesia akan mengatakan bahwa mereka akan menabung kalau ada uang lebih. Dan anehnya, sangat jarang sekali mereka memiliki uang lebih. Dan akibatnya, merekapun jarang menabung.

Jadi, kapankah sebenarnya waktu yang tepat untuk menabung? Jawabnya adalah ketika pertama kali anda menerima uang. Seharusnya, anda sudah membuat rencana untuk menyisihkan beberapa persen pendapatan untuk menabung.

Awalnya memang akan sangat sulit melakukan ini, tapi jika dibiasakan tentu akan menjadi mudah. Bahkan jika kita sesekali melihat saldo tabungan kita, biasanya kita akan semakin terpacu untuk menabung lebih banyak dan lebih banyak lagi.

Apalagi jika dikemudian hari tabungan itu benar-benar bermanfaat untuk kita, wah akan jadi nilai yang tak terhingga jadinya.

Maka, mulailah merencanakan dana masa depan anda mulai sekarang. Tung Desem Waringin pernah memberikan saran untuk menyisihkan 20% pendapatan untuk investasi atau ditabung. Jika anda merasa kesulitan, anda bisa memulai dengan 10% pendapatan terlebih dahulu. Setelah itu baru deh ditambah sedikit demi sedikit.

Jika hal ini rutin anda lakukan tiap bulan, maka saat anda sudah tak mampu bekerja lagi, tabungan investasi anda mungkin sudah mampu membiayai kehidupan anda.


Kenapa ikut Asuransi?


Mungkin saat ini masih belum banyak orang yang sadar asuransi. Ya, ini juga akibat dari para agen asuransi terdahulu yang memberi janji jauh dari kenyataan. Padahal asuransi sekarang benar-benar berbeda.

Apakah anda memiliki impian saat ini? Mungkin menyekolahkan anak hingga tingkat yang paling tinggi, memiliki dana pensiun atau ingin memberi peninggalan terbaik saat meninggal nanti.

Lalu apa yang anda lakukan untuk mewujudkan impian itu? Cara yang biasanya ditempuh adalah dengan menabung. Menyimpan uang agar bisa dipergunakan di hari depan.

Misalnya pak Antasari mulai mengatur keuangan dan menyisihkan 1 juta per bulan untuk tabungan masa depan. Setiap bulan pak Antasari menyisihkan uangnya hingga 10 tahun dan uangnya sudah terkumpul sangat banyak apalagi ditambah bunga atau bagi hasil jika menggunakan system syariah.

Ilustrasi diatas adalah yang terjadi jika pak Antasari menabung di bank. Hal yang sama juga terjadi di asuransi. Kita misalkan pak Azhar ikut asuransi dan membayar premi setiap bulan 1 juta hingga 10 tahun dan di akhir masa menabung, pak Azhar juga akan menikmati hasil yang sama dengan pak Antasari.

Tapi….

Ternyata kenyatan berkata lain. Di tahun ke 3 pak Antasari dan pak Azhar terkena resiko sakit secara bersamaan. Keduanya harus dirawat di RS karena menderita sakit keras.

pak Antasari langsung mengambil seluruh tabungannya, hutang saudara dan menjual beberapa aset untuk menutupi biaya pengobatan.

Berbeda dengan pak Azhar yang hanya perlu masuk ke RS dan melakukan perawatan dengan tenang tanpa beban pikiran. Kenapa? Karena seluruh biaya rumah sakit di tanggung oleh Perusahaan Asuransi.

Setelah keluar dari RS, pak Antasari tak sanggup lagi bekerja, tabungannya pun tak lagi bertambah dan dia hanya pasrah menghadapi hari-hari tuanya.

pak Azhar juga sama, tak mampu lagi bekerja, tapi tabungannya terus bertambah karena diisi langsung oleh Perusahaan Asuransi.

Jika anda boleh memilih, anda ingin menjadi siapa?


Kanz al-Mâl (Menimbun Harta)


Syariah Investasi. Kanzu adalah mashdar dari kanaza–yaknizu–kanz[an]. Al-Kanzu secara bahasa artinya harta yang dipendam.1 Al-Kanzu juga merupakan sebutan untuk harta yang disimpan di dalam kotak dan sebutan untuk apa saja yang disimpan di dalamnya.2 Dalam pembicaraan orang Arab, al-kanzu artinya adalah apa saja yang dikumpulkan sebagian atas sebagian yang lain, baik di dalam tanah atau di atas tanah.3 Harta yang dikumpulkan itu untuk ditimbun, yaitu dikumpulkan dan disimpan. Dengan demikian, al-kanzu adalah harta yang dikumpulkan dan disimpan, baik di dalam atau di atas tanah.4

Pengumpulan harta, khususnya uang, oleh seseorang itu ada dua bentuk: menabung dan menimbun. Jika seseorang mengumpulkan uang dan menyimpannya dengan tujuan untuk membiayai suatu rencana tertentu (misal: untuk membangun rumah, membeli kendaraan, menikah, naik haji dan sebagainya) maka pengumpulan uang semacam itu disebut menabung. Sebaliknya, jika seseorang mengumpulkan uang dan menyimpannya semata-mata hanya mengumpulkan dan menyimpannya tanpa ada rencana tertentu, pengumpulan seperti itu disebut menimbun.

Penimbunan uang akan berpengaruh terhadap perekonomian secara umum. Penimbunan uang itu akan mempengaruhi sirkulasi dan pertukaran harta di tengah masyarakat, dan akhrinya akan mempengaruhi jalannya roda perekonomian. Hal itu karena pendapatan seseorang atau lembaga, tidak lain, bersumber dari orang atau lembaga lain; alat pertukarannya adalah uang. Jika seseorang menimbun uang, itu artinya uang itu tidak masuk ke pasar. Karena penimbunan itu, sirkulasi harta di masyarakat pun terganggu. Pada taraf tertentu, jika jumlah uang yang ditimbun banyak, roda perekonomian pun akan berjalan sangat lambat dan akibatnya perekonomian akan merosot.

Namun, bahaya itu terjadi dari penimbunan uang bukan, dari menabung uang. Sebab, uang yang ditabung itu pada waktunya akan dibelanjakan sehingga pertukaran harta terjadi sehingga sirkulasi kekayaan tetap terjadi di masyarakat dan roda perekonomian tetap berjalan.

Islam membolehkan seseorang menabung uang untuk membiayai suatu keperluan yang ia rencanakan. Islam hanya mewajibkan pengeluaran zakat dari uang yang ditabung itu jika sudah mencapai batas nishâb dan berlalu haulnya. Sebaliknya, Islam mengharamkan penimbunan emas dan perak. Pada saat diharamkan, emas dan perak menjadi alat tukar dan standar bagi tenaga, jasa atau manfaat suatu harta. Atas dasar itu, larangan penimbunan emas dan perak itu juga terkait dengan fungsinya sebagai alat tukar. Artinya, larangan itu juga mencakup larangan terhadap penimbunan uang secara umum.

Allah Swt. berfirman:

وَالَّذِينَ يَكْنِزُونَ الذَّهَبَ وَالْفِضَّةَ وَلاَ يُنْفِقُونَهَا فِي سَبِيلِ اللهِ فَبَشِّرْهُمْ بِعَذَابٍ أَلِيمٍ

Orang-orang yang menimbun emas dan perak serta tidak menafkahkannya di jalan Allah, kepada mereka beritahukanlah bahwa mereka akan mendapat siksaan yang sangat pedih. (QS at-Taubah [9]: 34).


Adanya ancaman berupa siksaan yang pedih atas orang yang menimbun emas dan perak merupakan qarînah (indikasi) yang menunjukkan bahwa larangan itu bersifat tegas (jâzim). Dengan demikian, menimbun emas dan perak hukumnya haram. Keharaman itu bersifat pasti dan umum, alasannya:

Pertama: ayat ini bersifat umum berlaku untuk semua penimbunan emas dan perak. Keharaman menimbun emas dan perak dalam ayat ini ditunjukkan dengan penunjukan yang pasti. Penerapan larangan menimbun dalam ayat ini hanya untuk emas dan perak yang tidak dikeluarkan zakatnya, atau dengan kata lain membolehkan penimbunan emas dan perak setelah dikeluarkan zakatnya, memerlukan adanya nash lain yang memalingkan larangan dalam ayat ini atau yang me-nasakh-nya. Padahal tidak terdapat nash yang memalingkannya atau me-nasakh-nya. Adapun riwayat yang menyatakan bahwa emas dan perak yang dikumpulkan baik yang dipendam atau tidak, jika dikeluarkan zakatnya tidak termasuk penimbunan yang dilarang, semuanya bukanlah hadis yang sahih. Sebabnya, riwayat-riwayat itu adalah riwayat mawqûf, yakni sanad-nya berhenti pada Sahabat dan tidak sampai kepada Nabi saw.

Kedua: ath-Thabari meriwayatkan berturut-turut dari: al-Hasan, Abd ar-Razaq, Ma‘mar dari Qatadah, Syahr bin Hawsyab dari Abu Umamah bahwa ia berkata: Seorang laki-laki dari kalangan Ahlush Shuffah meninggal dunia. Di sakunya terdapat uang satu dinar. Rasulullah saw. bersabda, “Kayyah (satu stempel dari api).” Kemudian seorang Ahlush Shuffah yang lain meninggal dunia dan di sakunya terdapat dua dinar. Rasulullah saw bersabda, Kayyatân (Dua stempel dari api).”

Imam Ahmad meriwayatkannya dari Ali bin Abi Thalib dan Ibn Mas‘ud. Hal itu karena keduanya adalah orang yang hidup dari sedekah, sementara keduanya memiliki emas. Sabda Rasul saw, kayyah dan kayyatân, itu mengisyaratkan pada larangan menimbun emas dan perak di atas. Sabda Rasul itu juga mengisyaratkan bahwa keduanya telah menimbun emas. Hal itu karena keduanya adalah Ahlush Shuffah yang kehidupannya telah dipenuhi dari harta sedekah (zakat). Itu menandakan bahwa keduanya menyimpan emas tersebut bukan dalam rangka menabung karena kehidupannya telah dijamin dari shadaqah. Jumlah satu dan dua dinar jelas belum memenuhi nishâb zakat. Ini menunjukkan bahwa penimbunan emas dan perak yang terkena ancaman ayat di atas bukan hanya dalam jumlah yang sudah mencapai nishâb dan tidak dikeluarkan zakatnya. Setiap penimbunan emas dan perak berapapun terkena ancaman ayat di atas dan hukumnya haram, meski hanya satu atau dua dinar.

Ketiga: ancaman ayat di atas terkait dengan dua macam aktivitas: aktivitas menimbun emas dan perak; dan aktivitas tidak membelan-jakannya di jalan Allah. Artinya, ada orang yang tidak menimbun emas dan perak tetapi tidak membelanjakannya di jalan Allah; orang yang menimbun emas dan perak dan tidak membelanjakannya di jalan Allah; dan orang yang menimbun emas dan perak saja meski ia membelanjakan sebagian hartanya di jalan Allah. Semuanya terkena ancaman ayat di atas. Al-Qurthubi mengatakan di dalam tafsirnya, “Siapa yang tidak menimbun, sementara ia menahan pembelanjaanya di jalan Allah, ia mesti demikian juga (terkena ancaman ayat tersebut)”.5 Frasa di jalan Allah (fî sabîlillâh) di dalam al-Quran, jika dikaitkan dengan infak, maksudnya adalah jihad fî sabîlillâh, bukan yang lain.

Keempat: Imam Bukhari meriwayatkan dari Zaid bin Wahab tentang perbedaan pendapat Muawiyah bin Abi Sufyan dengan Abu Dzar tentang ayat di atas. Muawiyah berkata, “Ayat ini bukan untuk kita, melainkan ayat ini hanya untuk Ahlul Kitab.” Abu Dzar membantah dengan mengatakan, “Sungguh, ayat ini untuk kita dan mereka.”

Muawiyah lalu melaporkan Abu Dazar kepada Khalifah Utsman. Lalu Khalifah memanggil Abu Dazar ke Madinah, dan berlangsunglah peristiwa seperti yang diceritakan dalam riwayat tersebut. Perbedaan pendapat yang terjadi antara Muawiyah dan Abu Dzar adalah untuk siapa ayat tersebut diturunkan. Seandainya saat itu sudah masyhur riwayat dari Nabi saw. bahwa emas dan perak yang telah dikeluarkan zakatnya tidak termasuk al-kanzu, tentu Muawiyah akan ber-hujjah dengannya dan Abu Dzar pun akan diam karenanya. Namun, sampai ketika Abu Dzar menghadap Khalifah Utsman sekalipun, tidak disampaikan riwayat itu meski banyak dari Sahabat yang masih tinggal di Madinah.

Kelima: kanzu adz-dzahab wa al-fidhah secara bahasa maknanya mengumpulkan/menimbun emas dan perak dan menyimpannya baik di dalam tanah maupun di atas tanah. Lafal al-Quran dimaknai dengan makna bahasanya saja, kecuali terdapat makna syariah yang dinyatakan oleh nash; dalam kondisi tersebut makna syariah dikedepankan atas makna bahasa. Lafal al-kanzu tidak terdapat makna syariahnya. Karena itu, lafal ini dalam ayat di atas harus dimaknai menurut makna bahasanya saja.

Dengan demikian, kanzu adz-dzahab wa al-fidhah (menimbun emas dan perak) atau menimbun uang adalah mengumpulkannya dan menyimpannya baik di dalam tanah maupun di atas tanah. Hal itu dilakukan semata untuk mengumpulkan dan menyimpannya saja, bukan untuk menabung dalam rangka membiayai suatu keperluan yang direncanakan. Semua bentuk penimbunan emas dan perak atau penimbunan uang itu hukumnya haram dan pelakunya diancam dengan siksaan yang amat pedih di akhriat kelak.

Wallâh a‘lam bi ash-shawâb.

Catatan Kaki:

  1. Ar-Razi, Mukhtâr ash-Shihâh, I/124, ed. Mahmud Khathir, Maktabah Lubnan Nasyirun, Beirut, thaba’ah jadidah. 1415-1995
  2. Ibn Manzhur, Lisân al-‘Arab, V/401, Dar Shadir,
  3. Beirut, cet. I. tt3 Ibn Jarir ath-Thabari, Tafsîr ath-Thabarî, X/121, Dar al-Fikr, Beirut. 1405 H
  4. Al-Minawi, Faydh al-Qadîr, V/29, Maktabah at-Tijariyah al-Kubra, Mesir, cet. I. 1356 H
  5. Al-Qurthubi, Tafsîr al-Qurthubî, VIII/128, ed. Muhammad Abdul Halim al-Barduni, Dar asy-Sya’b, Kaero, cet. II. 1372

Sumber : Majalah Al Waie edisi Mei 2007